Micro module 9: Reading for ninth edition


Micro module 9: Reading for ninth edition

Author
Message
NEAS
Supreme Being
Supreme Being (5.9K reputation)Supreme Being (5.9K reputation)Supreme Being (5.9K reputation)Supreme Being (5.9K reputation)Supreme Being (5.9K reputation)Supreme Being (5.9K reputation)Supreme Being (5.9K reputation)Supreme Being (5.9K reputation)Supreme Being (5.9K reputation)

Group: Administrators
Posts: 4.3K, Visits: 1.3K

Microeconomics, Module 9, “Welfare Economics and the Gains from Trade”

Micro module 9: Reading for ninth edition

(The attached PDF file has better formatting.)

{The Landsburg textbook is excellent. We say to read certain sections and to skip others. This does not mean that certain sections are better; it means that the homework assignments and exam problems are based on the sections that you must read for this course. Some skipped sections are fascinating but are not tested.}

This module covers consumers’ surplus and producers’ surplus. Chapter 8 of Landsburg’s text has other items as well, not all of which are not tested on the final exam. We specify here what you must know.

Read the introduction, which is excellent. A statement that a certain policy is good or bad is incomplete: almost every policy is good for some people and bad for others. Landsburg shows how to analyze policies.

Read section 8.1. Know the difference between value and surplus; see the definitions of value on the side of page 220 and the definitions of consumers’ surplus and producers’ surplus on the sides of page 224 and 227.

●    The consumers’ surplus is the area under the demand curve down to the price paid and out to the quantity demanded (page 224).
●    The producers’ surplus is the area above the supply curve up to the price paid and out to the quantity supplied (page 227).

Landsburg calculates consumers’ surplus and producers’ surplus from discrete supply and demand schedules. The homework assignments and final exam problems also use linear supply and demand curves. The areas representing consumers’ surplus and producers’ surplus are right triangles, whose area is ½ × height × width. The concepts and overview postings for Modules 11 and 12 show the procedure to calculate the surplus for various scenarios. Both the discrete schedules and the areas of triangles are shown in the practice problems, and the same procedures are used on the final exam.

On page 223, Exhibit 8.2 shows the value as an area on a graph. To avoid calculus, Landsburg works out the figures by summing schedules. Using calculus, we integrate under a curve and above a straight line. Most final exam questions use linear demand curves and marginal cost curves and simple geometry to find the area of a right triangle. The final exam does not test your mathematical abilities, so it does not use more complex cost curves and demand curves.

From Section 8.2 (“The efficiency criterion,” starting on page 230), skip the first sub-section on pages 230-231. You will use the efficiency criterion, but you need not evaluate it. This is a course on economics, not on politics. This sub-section is excellent, but no final exam problems are asked on it. You learn much from these pages, and they are well worth reading, but they are not required for this course.

Read “consumers’ surplus and the efficiency criterion,” on pages 231-232 and “the effect of a sales tax” on pages 232-234. The concepts and overview posting shows the core diagram for this section. The final exam tests the effect of a sales tax or an excise tax on consumers’ surplus and producers’ surplus.

Read the material on dead weight loss on pages 234-227. The final exam problems test sales taxes, excise taxes, and subsidies; read pages 241-243. In each case, you determine the change in consumers’ surplus, producers’ surplus, and the dead weight loss.

You may skip the section on Hidden Assumptions on pages 239 and the section on “other normative criteria” on pages 239-40. They is worth reading, but these assumptions are not tested on the final exam.

Price ceilings and tariffs are not tested on the final exam. Landsburg's discussion of robbery is interesting and worth reading, but it is not tested on the final exam.

Graphics for price subsidies and price ceilings are in the concepts and overview posting on the discussion forum, but the final exam does not test this material and there are no homework assignments from it. Price ceilings were used in the United States during the oil crisis of 1972, but even politicians now acknowledge that they harm the economy.

The material on tariffs is worth reading to understand the economic perspective on outsourcing and international trade, but it is not tested on the final exam. So much Congressional energy is wasted on blaming China for U.S. economic ills. Economists say: "If China wants to sell us goods below cost, why should we complain?" If someone offered to sell you running shoes for half the price they sell in stores, should you complain that this person is unfairly subsidizing the sale?

Read the section on the “diamond-water paradox” on pages 250-251. Skip the “labor theory of value”; unless you are a Marxist economist, you don’t need Landsburg to tell you this is wrong.

Skip section 8.4. This is all theoretical; Landsburg says that economists have proved the results, but they too complex to be reviewed here. This section says that capitalism works well; it might be the best economic system around. Western economists believe this, and we also agree.

Western thinkers have often wondered how we can know if we are prejudiced; after all, Marxist economists said that communism was the best economic system around. Max Weber conjectured that scientists and scholars in an open university are relatively free of prejudice. This sounds good, but most academicians have views that are at odds with those of simple economics. We believe in the invisible hand theory, but the final exam doesn’t test this section.

Question: Communism has collapsed; are there still politicians and intellectuals who don’t believe in free markets and the invisible hand theory?

Answer: Look at the European Union. In the twenty years since Communism has collapsed, leaders of various European countries (France, Germany, Belgium) has built up a system that is the opposite of Landsburg’s textbook. Even now, with the poverty of the European Union compared to the vitality of India, China, Singapore, and other Asian nations, the leaders of France and some other European countries continue to espouse its ideas. Even Britain has succumbed to the European social welfare ideal, and it is only now trying to rescue itself. Over the past two years, the U.S. has reversed its support of individualism and private business, and it is moving toward the European system.

Question: Are you saying that the goals of the European Union are not good?

Answer: We say nothing about the goals. The goal of a peaceful continent is wonderful; but the attempt to suppress free markets will cause that continent to sink. The ideal would be free markets along with political freedom and peace.

The material on macroeconomic theory is covered better in Barro’s textbook. Many candidates are taking both micro and macro on-line courses; we cover this material in macro, where it is more relevant, not in micro. Landsburg and Barro have the same perspective, and we avoid duplicating material in these courses.

Question: Brealey and Myers, Landsburg, and Barro all have the same perspective. Is this expected?

Answer: Until thirty years ago, Western intellectuals argued about the best economic and financial systems. The Communist world seemed to be getting stronger; the Europeans (France, Germany) and Asians (Japan, South Korea, Singapore, Taiwan, Hong Kong) seemed to be over-taking the United States. The free market perspective in these three textbooks seemed a poor match for the central planning of Communist countries, the social model of the Europeans, or the directed economies of the Asians. But few now believe that the alternatives out-perform free markets. Even countries who oppose free markets speak of other objectives (justice, equity, equality), not pure economic or financial reasons for alternative systems. Economic and financial theory has converged; Brealey and Myers, Landsburg, and Barro reflect the current consensus.

But politics trumps economics. High taxes on labor ruin economies (see the modules on labor economics in microeconomics and macroeconomics courses), but western countries continue raising taxes.

The summary at the end covers the whole chapter; read the parts covered here. Skip the Appendix to Chapter 8. We summarize the appendix in the Concepts and Overview posting, but we don’t test this material on the final exam.

Review question 11 on page 266. This question is not easy; work through Landsburg's graphs to see the dead weight loss.

Review questions 14 and 15 on page 266. These questions are similar, but slight differences in the ration tickets affect who bears the losses.

Review question 23, 26, and 27 on pages 268-269. The final exam problems are similar: the exam problem gives supply and demand curves and the amount of a tax or subsidy. You work out consumers’ surplus and producers’ surplus with and without the tax or subsidy and the resulting dead weight loss.



Attachments
Micro.Module9.readings.Ed9.pdf (512 views, 49.00 KB)
Edited 6 Years Ago by NEAS
NEAS
Supreme Being
Supreme Being (5.9K reputation)Supreme Being (5.9K reputation)Supreme Being (5.9K reputation)Supreme Being (5.9K reputation)Supreme Being (5.9K reputation)Supreme Being (5.9K reputation)Supreme Being (5.9K reputation)Supreme Being (5.9K reputation)Supreme Being (5.9K reputation)

Group: Administrators
Posts: 4.3K, Visits: 1.3K
NEAS - 10/15/2013 2:06:20 PM

Microeconomics, Module 9, “Welfare Economics and the Gains from Trade”

Micro module 9: Reading for ninth edition

(The attached PDF file has better formatting.)

{The Landsburg textbook is excellent. We say to read certain sections and to skip others. This does not mean that certain sections are better; it means that the homework assignments and exam problems are based on the sections that you must read for this course. Some skipped sections are fascinating but are not tested.}

This module covers consumers’ surplus and producers’ surplus. Chapter 8 of Landsburg’s text has other items as well, not all of which are not tested on the final exam. We specify here what you must know.

Read the introduction, which is excellent. A statement that a certain policy is good or bad is incomplete: almost every policy is good for some people and bad for others. Landsburg shows how to analyze policies.

Read section 8.1. Know the difference between value and surplus; see the definitions of value on the side of page 220 and the definitions of consumers’ surplus and producers’ surplus on the sides of page 224 and 227.

●    The consumers’ surplus is the area under the demand curve down to the price paid and out to the quantity demanded (page 224).
●    The producers’ surplus is the area above the supply curve up to the price paid and out to the quantity supplied (page 227).

Landsburg calculates consumers’ surplus and producers’ surplus from discrete supply and demand schedules. The homework assignments and final exam problems also use linear supply and demand curves. The areas representing consumers’ surplus and producers’ surplus are right triangles, whose area is ½ × height × width. The concepts and overview postings for Modules 11 and 12 show the procedure to calculate the surplus for various scenarios. Both the discrete schedules and the areas of triangles are shown in the practice problems, and the same procedures are used on the final exam.

On page 223, Exhibit 8.2 shows the value as an area on a graph. To avoid calculus, Landsburg works out the figures by summing schedules. Using calculus, we integrate under a curve and above a straight line. Most final exam questions use linear demand curves and marginal cost curves and simple geometry to find the area of a right triangle. The final exam does not test your mathematical abilities, so it does not use more complex cost curves and demand curves.

From Section 8.2 (“The efficiency criterion,” starting on page 230), skip the first sub-section on pages 230-231. You will use the efficiency criterion, but you need not evaluate it. This is a course on economics, not on politics. This sub-section is excellent, but no final exam problems are asked on it. You learn much from these pages, and they are well worth reading, but they are not required for this course.

Read “consumers’ surplus and the efficiency criterion,” on pages 231-232 and “the effect of a sales tax” on pages 232-234. The concepts and overview posting shows the core diagram for this section. The final exam tests the effect of a sales tax or an excise tax on consumers’ surplus and producers’ surplus.

Read the material on dead weight loss on pages 234-227. The final exam problems test sales taxes, excise taxes, and subsidies; read pages 241-243. In each case, you determine the change in consumers’ surplus, producers’ surplus, and the dead weight loss.

You may skip the section on Hidden Assumptions on pages 239 and the section on “other normative criteria” on pages 239-40. They is worth reading, but these assumptions are not tested on the final exam.

Price ceilings and tariffs are not tested on the final exam. Landsburg's discussion of robbery is interesting and worth reading, but it is not tested on the final exam.

Graphics for price subsidies and price ceilings are in the concepts and overview posting on the discussion forum, but the final exam does not test this material and there are no homework assignments from it. Price ceilings were used in the United States during the oil crisis of 1972, but even politicians now acknowledge that they harm the economy.

The material on tariffs is worth reading to understand the economic perspective on outsourcing and international trade, but it is not tested on the final exam. So much Congressional energy is wasted on blaming China for U.S. economic ills. Economists say: "If China wants to sell us goods below cost, why should we complain?" If someone offered to sell you running shoes for half the price they sell in stores, should you complain that this person is unfairly subsidizing the sale?

Read the section on the “diamond-water paradox” on pages 250-251. Skip the “labor theory of value”; unless you are a Marxist economist, you don’t need Landsburg to tell you this is wrong.

Skip section 8.4. This is all theoretical; Landsburg says that economists have proved the results, but they too complex to be reviewed here. This section says that capitalism works well; it might be the best economic system around. Western economists believe this, and we also agree.

Western thinkers have often wondered how we can know if we are prejudiced; after all, Marxist economists said that communism was the best economic system around. Max Weber conjectured that scientists and scholars in an open university are relatively free of prejudice. This sounds good, but most academicians have views that are at odds with those of simple economics. We believe in the invisible hand theory, but the final exam doesn’t test this section.

Question: Communism has collapsed; are there still politicians and intellectuals who don’t believe in free markets and the invisible hand theory?

Answer: Look at the European Union. In the twenty years since Communism has collapsed, leaders of various European countries (France, Germany, Belgium) has built up a system that is the opposite of Landsburg’s textbook. Even now, with the poverty of the European Union compared to the vitality of India, China, Singapore, and other Asian nations, the leaders of France and some other European countries continue to espouse its ideas. Even Britain has succumbed to the European social welfare ideal, and it is only now trying to rescue itself. Over the past two years, the U.S. has reversed its support of individualism and private business, and it is moving toward the European system.

Question: Are you saying that the goals of the European Union are not good?

Answer: We say nothing about the goals. The goal of a peaceful continent is wonderful; but the attempt to suppress free markets will cause that continent to sink. The ideal would be free markets along with political freedom and peace.

The material on macroeconomic theory is covered better in Barro’s textbook. Many candidates are taking both micro and macro on-line courses; we cover this material in macro, where it is more relevant, not in micro. Landsburg and Barro have the same perspective, and we avoid duplicating material in these courses.

Question: Brealey and Myers, Landsburg, and Barro all have the same perspective. Is this expected?

Answer: Until thirty years ago, Western intellectuals argued about the best economic and financial systems. The Communist world seemed to be getting stronger; the Europeans (France, Germany) and Asians (Japan, South Korea, Singapore, Taiwan, Hong Kong) seemed to be over-taking the United States. The free market perspective in these three textbooks seemed a poor match for the central planning of Communist countries, the social model of the Europeans, or the directed economies of the Asians. But few now believe that the alternatives out-perform free markets. Even countries who oppose free markets speak of other objectives (justice, equity, equality), not pure economic or financial reasons for alternative systems. Economic and financial theory has converged; Brealey and Myers, Landsburg, and Barro reflect the current consensus.

But politics trumps economics. High taxes on labor ruin economies (see the modules on labor economics in microeconomics and macroeconomics courses), but western countries continue raising taxes.

The summary at the end covers the whole chapter; read the parts covered here. Skip the Appendix to Chapter 8. We summarize the appendix in the Concepts and Overview posting, but we don’t test this material on the final exam.

Review question 11 on page 266. This question is not easy; work through Landsburg's graphs to see the dead weight loss.

Review questions 14 and 15 on page 266. These questions are similar, but slight differences in the ration tickets affect who bears the losses.

Review question 23, 26, and 27 on pages 268-269. The final exam problems are similar: the exam problem gives supply and demand curves and the amount of a tax or subsidy. You work out consumers’ surplus and producers’ surplus with and without the tax or subsidy and the resulting dead weight loss.



 

GO
Merge Selected
Merge into selected topic...



Merge into merge target...



Merge into a specific topic ID...





Reading This Topic


Login
Existing Account
Email Address:


Password:


Social Logins

  • Login with twitter
  • Login with twitter
Select a Forum....











































































































































































































































Neas-Seminars

Search