Microeconomics, Module 4: “Consumers in the marketplace”
Micro module 4: Readings for Tenth Edition: Landsburg, Chapter 4
(The attached PDF file has better formatting.)
Module 4 applies indifference curves to practical scenarios. Changes in income and price affect the quantity demanded by consumers. We discuss wealth effects (income effects), substitution effects, and elasticities.
Know how changes in the price of a good affect the slope of the budget line (Exhibit 4-5).
Barro (macroeconomics) also uses wealth effects and substitution effects; the concepts are the same.
For the microeconomics course, know the following about elasticities:
(1) An elasticity is the proportional change (percentage change) in the dependent variable divided by the proportional change (percentage change) in the independent variable. The dependent variable may be the quantity demanded or the quantity supplied; the independent variable may be the price, the consumer’s income, or the price of another good. If a 1% increase in price causes the quantity demanded to decrease by 2%, the price elasticity of demand is –2.
(2) We discuss four elasticities in this course:
● price elasticity of demand (quantity demanded / price)
● income elasticity of demand (quantity demanded / income)
● cross elasticity of demand (quantity demanded / price of another good)
● price elasticity of supply (quantity supplied / price)
(3) The fundamental equation is =
In later chapters, we discuss the relation of elasticity and price for monopolies.
(4) If the demand curve is linear, the price elasticity of demand is high when price is high and quantity is low and low when price is low and quantity is high. If the demand curve is of the form P × Q = k, the price elasticity of demand is constant. Other postings explain why we expect the price elasticity of demand to rise or fall as the price changes.
(5) When the relation is perfectly elastic (η = ∞ or –∞), the graph is horizontal (flat); when the relation is completely inelastic (η = 0), the graph is vertical.
Question: When dealing with percentage changes, we normally take logarithms. What is the relation of the logarithm to the elasticity?
Answer: If ln Q = α + β × ln P + ε, then by taking the total derivative, we get
∂(ln Q) = ∂(α + β × ln P + ε) ➾ ∂Q/Q = β × ∂P/P ➾ η = β.
Economists use elasticities, which are not distorted by changes in the unit of measurement.
Focus on the following items for this module:
A good is normal if an increase in income increases the quantity demanded. A good is inferior if an increase in income decreases the quantity demanded. Engel curves show the relation between income and quantity demanded.
Whether a good is normal or inferior depends on the consumer:
● poor persons buy more pasta as their incomes increase
● rich persons buy higher quality foods and less pasta as their incomes increase
A good may be normal when income is low but inferior when income is high.
Illustration: Maccaroni and cheese, inexpensive jewelry, used cars, and cheeseburgers are normal goods for low income consumers and inferior goods for high income consumer. Yachts, lamb chops, and residential land are normal goods even for wealthy consumers.
Final exam: Expect a question asking you to derive the price elasticity of demand or supply at a given point from the demand or supply curve. The demand or supply curve may be any form, though we generally use linear curves.
Final exam: Expect a question asking if the price elasticity of demand is higher or lower as price or quantity increases or decreases (if the demand curve is linear).
Homework assignments: The homework asks you to discuss the elasticity of insurance, to see if you have read the textbook.
Landsburg shows how to derive the demand curve from the indifference curves, seeing how the consumer’s optimum changes as the price of the good changes (Exhibit 4-8). The analysis is complex and is rarely used; we do not test it on the final exam.
For a Giffen good, the quantity demanded increases when its price increases. A Giffen good does not contradict the law of demand, since the pure substitution effect obeys the relation: quantity demanded falls as the price rises. If the good is inferior and consumers spend most of their income on this good, it may be Giffen. Giffen goods occur in theory, but rarely (if ever) in practice. An economist named Giffen theorized that farmers ate more potatoes during a mid-19th century Irish famine when the price of potatoes rose because they could not afford more expensive foods. Many economists doubt that this happened. For consumers in the U.S. and other industrialized countries, there are no Giffen goods.
Know section 4.3; these effects occur in real life and are tested on the final exam. Exhibit 4-11 helps you visualize the two effects.
Landsburg shows graphs for compensated demand curves and uncompensated demand curves. We do not test these on the final exam. Skip the section on compensated demand curves.
Know the formulas for the 4.4.1 Income Elasticity of Demand and for the 4.4.2 Price Elasticity of Demand. Elasticities are discussed in many modules and are frequently tested on the final exam.
Review Questions R1, R2, R3, R4, R8, R9, R13, R14, R15, R16; they help you understand the relations among the curves.
Review Exercise N1. The final exam may give a relation like this and compute the quantity and price of the goods. (The final exam assumes you know calculus.)
Review Exercise N2. The final exam may give the values of the parameters and ask for the income elasticity (see Part B of this exercise).
Review Exercises N3, N4. The final exam does not ask you to derive formulas but it does test the relations in the text. The final exam may give a linear demand curve and ask for the price elasticity of demand. Alternatively, the final exam may give the price elasticity of demand at one price, say the demand curve is linear, and ask for the price elasticity of demand at another point.
Review end of chapter problem 1. You don't buy the same basket of goods (wine and roses) on Monday, Tuesday, and Wednesday. Work through each part of this problem.
Review end of chapter problems 3, 16, 17, 18, 19, 20, 22abc, 23, 26, 27bc, 28, 37abc, 41.
Review end of chapter problem 39. Landsburg says that without seat belts, drivers are afraid of being hurt in traffic accidents, so they drive more carefully. With seat belts, drivers feel safer, so they drive faster. Accident victims include the person hit, not just the person speeding, so fatalities increase. Whether Landsburg is correct is much debated, but the moral is clear: even changes that are assumed to be good (like seat belt laws) may have inadvertent incentives that are bad.